25765 Corporate Finance:
Payout policy
University of Technology Sydney
Spring 2023
1 / 31
Overview
A firm can retain free cash flows to invest in new projects or
to build up cash reserves. It can also distribute the cash to
shareholders.
There are 2 major ways of distributions: dividends and
repurchases.
Suppose ABC Co. has $20 million in FCF, 10 million shares
outstanding, no debt, and Re = 12%.
It expects to generate future FCFs of $48 million per year
thereafter.
How should a firm design its payout policy
2 / 31
Payout policy irrelevance
Method 1: Dividend payout with excess cash
The cum-dividend share price is:
Scum-div = Current dividend + PV of future dividends
=
$20 million
10 million +
1
0.12
×
$48 million
10 million = $42
After paying out the current dividend, the ex-dividend share price
falls to:
Sex-div = PV of future dividends
=
1
0.12
×
$48 million
10 million = $40
In a perfect market, the share price drops by the amount of dividend
paid out when the stock begins to trade ex-dividend.
3 / 31
Method 2: Share repurchase (1)
Suppose that ABC instead uses the $20 million to repurchase its
shares on the open market. It can repurchase:
$20 million
$42 per share = 0.476 million shares
After the repurchase, ABC’s market value of assets also decreases
to:
$42 × 10 million $20 million
|
{z
}
cash for repurchase
= $400 million
Post-repurchase share price is now:
$400 million
10 million 0.476 million = $42
4 / 31
Method 2: Share repurchase (2)
After the repurchase, the future dividends would rise to:
$48 million
10 million 0.476 million = $5.04 per share
The stream of dividends is valued at:
S =
$5.04
0.12
= $42
So, shareholders are indifferent between participating and not par_x005f ticipating in ABC’s repurchase exercise.
5 / 31
Homemade payouts (1)
In perfect markets, an open market repurchase has no effect
on the share price.
Investors are indifferent between the $20 million distributed
via dividends or repurchases.
By re-investing dividends or selling shares, investors can
replicate either payout method on their own.
If ABC repurchases shares, investors who like dividends can
sell shares.
If ABC pays out dividends, investors who do not like dividends
can buy stock.
6 / 31
Homemade payouts (2)
How would an investor who owns 2000 shares create a homemade
dividend of $9000 per year First, we show that the investor will
now receive a dividend of:
2000 shares × $2 = $4000
She is short of $9000 $4000 = $5000 today. So, she can make up
for it by selling:
$5000 = 125 shares $40
In future years, she is left with 2000 shares 125 shares = 1875 shares.
At $4.80 dividend per share, she gets:
1875 shares × $4.80 = $9000 per year
7 / 31
Homemade payouts (3)
Suppose ABC chooses to pay out the $2 dividend per share. How ever, what can an investor who owns 2000 shares and dislikes div idends do Because she dislikes dividends, she can re-invest the
dividends into more stock at the ex-dividend price. She will then
have:
2000 shares + $4000
$40 = 2100 shares
Her portfolio value is now 2100 shares × $40 = $84000. If she had
accepted the dividends and done nothing, her portfolio value would
also be:
2000 shares × $40 + $4000 = $84000
8 / 31
Method 3: High dividend (1)
Suppose that ABC still has 10 million shares outstanding. It only
has $20 million in cash today, but it wants to pay $42 million more
in dividends. ABC wants to raise the entire $42 million by issuing
new equity. It can sell:
$42 million
$42 per share = 1 million shares
The new current dividend is now:
$20 million + $42 million
10 million + 1 million = $5.64 per share
9 / 31
Method 3: High dividend (2)
Future dividends are
$48 M
11M = $4.36 per share
So, the cum-dividend share price is:
Scum-div = $5.64 + $4.36
0.12
= $42
10 / 31
Dividend policy irrelevance (1)
Modigliani-Miller: In perfect markets, holding fixed a firm’s
investment policy, the firm’s dividend policy is irrelevant.
Tradeoff between current dividends ↑↓ and future dividends ↓↑
such that the initial stock price remains constant.
A firm’s free cash flows determine the level of payouts it can
make to investors.
The type of payout is irrelevant because investors can
manufacture their desired payout patterns.
11 / 31
Dividend policy irrelevance (2)
Dividend per share ($)
S ($) Year 0 Year 1 Year 2 . . .
Policy 1 42 2.00 4.80 4.80 . . .
Policy 2 42 0.00 5.04 5.04 . . .
Policy 3 42 4.50 4.50 4.50 . . .
Payout policy is irrelevant in perfect markets.
12 / 31
Dividends and taxes
Dividends and taxes (1)
In reality, there are taxes on dividends and capital gains.
Dividends are suboptimal from a tax perspective because τd is
often higher than τg .
In fact, long-term investors can defer capital gains taxes
indefinitely by not selling.
When τd > τg , raising cash via equity issuances to pay
dividends hurts shareholders.
Consider the setup on Slide 9 with τd = 40% and τg = 15%.
13 / 31
Dividends and taxes (2)
If ABC had not raised the extra cash, it would have paid out only
$20 million in dividends. Investors pay taxes on these dividends.
40% × $20 million = $8 million
But, equity value falls exactly by $20 million ex-dividend so investor
save some money on capital gains taxes.
15% × $20 million = $3 million
On net, investors pay $5 million in taxes due to the dividend payout.
14 / 31
Dividends and taxes (3)
Because ABC raised extra cash to pay a total of $62 million of
dividends, investors pay net taxes of:
(40% 15%) × $62 million = $15.5 million
Compared to the base case, investors paid extra taxes.
$15.5 million $5 million = $10.5 million
So, ABC destroyed $10.5 million out of the $42 million investment.
15 / 31
Dividend and taxes (4)
The tax impact of dividends is partly offset by savings on capital
gains tax. So, when τd 6 = τg , the effective dividend tax rate is not
exactly τd .
(Scum-div Sex-div) × (1 τg )
|
{z
}
after-tax loss
= DIV × (1 τd )
|
{z
}
after-tax gain
If after-tax loss > after-tax gain, then investors avoid the dividend
by selling the stock cum-dividend and buying it back ex-dividend.
If after-tax loss < after-tax gain, then investors rush to buy the stock
cum-dividend to capture the dividend, and sell it ex-dividend.
When after-tax loss = after-tax gain, there is no profitable arbitrage
at this equilibrium.
16 / 31
Dividend and taxes (5)
Rearranging the terms,
Scum-div Sex-div = DIV ×
1 τ
1 τ
d
g
= DIV ×
1
τd τg
1 τg
|
{z
}
τ
d
The effective dividend tax rate τd
measures the tax disadvantage of
dividends relative to capital gains.
17 / 31
Dividend and taxes (6)
Suppose τd = 39% and τg = 20%, then:
τd
=
0.39 0.20
1 0.20
= 23.75%
This means that, after taxes, every $1 of dividends is worth only:
(1 23.75%) × $1 = $0.7625 in capital gains
18 / 31
Clientele effects
19 / 31
Retention and payout
Retention and payout (1)
In perfect markets, once a firm has taken all positive-NPV
projects, it is indifferent between saving excess cash and
paying it out.
Rather than waste excess cash on negative-NPV projects, the
firm can purchase financial assets.
Because there are no transaction costs, buying or selling
financial assets does not affect firm value.
Modigliani-Miller: In perfect markets, the firm’s choice of
payout versus retention is irrelevant if it has access to
financial assets.
20 / 31
Retention and payout (2)
Suppose ABC Co. has $100000 in excess cash. ABC can invest the
cash in one-year Treasury bills at 6% interest, and use the cash to
pay a dividend next year. Alternatively, ABC can pay a dividend
immediately.
If ABC retains the cash, at year-end, it can pay a dividend of:
$100000 × 1.06 = $106000
If ABC pays a dividend immediately, shareholders can invest the
payout in Treasury bills themselves and receive at year-end:
$100000 × 1.06 = $106000
So, the retention-payout decision is irrelevant.
21 / 31
Retention and payout (3)
Suppose the same setup in Slide 21. But, the corporate tax rate is
35%, and ABC’s shareholders are tax-exempt. If ABC retains the
cash, it can only pay the after-tax return on the Treasury bills as
dividends at year-end.
$100000 + $100000 × 6% × (1 35%) = $103900
This is lower than the $106000 that the tax-exempt shareholders
could have earned if they invested in the Treasury bills themselves.
22 / 31
Retention and payout (4)
If ABC chooses to retain the $100000 permanently, what is the PV
of tax payments on the additional interest income
PV of extra tax payments = $100000 × 6% × 35%
6% = $35000
23 / 31
Retention and payout (5)
While some investors are tax-exempt, most individual investors must
pay taxes on interest, dividends, and capital gains. We now see how
investors’ personal taxes affect the tax disadvantage of retaining
cash.
Consider this simple example. A firm only has one asset, $100 cash.
It has two choices:
1. Pay out the cash as a dividend immediately and shut down.
2. Retain the cash permanently and invest it in Treasury bills at
rf
. Pay out annual dividends from its after-tax interest
income.
24 / 31
Retention and payout (6)
Choice #1: After paying out the dividend, the firm shuts down so
Sex-div becomes 0. Refer to Slide 16 for the below equation.
Scum-div =
=0
z
}|
{
Sex-div +DIV ×
_x0012_
1 τd
1 τg
_x0013_
= $100 ×
1 τd
1 τg
Choice #2: From its investment in the Treasury bills, the firm can
pay a perpetual after-tax dividend of:
DIV = $100 × rf × (1 τc )
where τc is the corporate tax rate
25 / 31
Retention and payout (7)
Choice #2 (cont’d): What price Sretain will an investor pay for this
firm Her cost of capital is the after-tax return that she could have
earned by investing in Treasury bills herself: rf × (1 τi).
Where τi
is the investor’s personal tax on interest income,
Sretain =
DIV × (1 τd )
rf × (1 τi)
=
$100 × rf × (1 τc ) × (1 τd )
rf × (1 τi)
= $100 ×
(1 τc ) × (1 τd )
(1 τi)
26 / 31
Retention and payout (8)
Choice #2 (cont’d): We now compare Sretain with Scum-div.
Sretain
Scum-div
=
$100 ×
(1 τc )×(1 τd )
(1 τi )
$100 ×
1 τd
1 τg
=
(1 τc ) × (1 τg )
(1 τi)
Moving Scum-div to the right-hand-side, and simplifying:
Sretain = Scum-div × (1 τ
retain)
where
τ
retain = 1
(1 τc ) × (1 τg )
(1 τi)
27 / 31
Retention and payout (9)
τ
retain = 1
(1 τc ) × (1 τg )
(1 τi)
This equation tells us 3 things:
1. The interest on retained cash is taxed twice.
2. For investors in a very high income tax bracket, τ
retain can be
near zero.
3. For tax-exempt investors, τ
retain = τc
28 / 31
Homework questions
Question 1
ABC Co. pays a regular dividend of $2.50 per share. Typ ically, ABC’s share price falls by $2.00 when the stock
goes ex-dividend. Suppose all investors face the same
τg = 20%, but they may pay different tax rates on div idends. Absent transaction costs, what is the highest τd
of an investor who can gain from capturing the dividend
29 / 31
Question 2
ABC Co. expects to generate $40 million in FCF per year
and will pay out these cash flows as regular dividends.
ABC has no debt, 10 million shares outstanding, and a
unlevered cost of capital of 10%. It now has $50 million
in excess cash and wants to use it to repurchase shares.
You own 4000 ABC shares, but you are unhappy with the
repurchase. You would have preferred ABC to pay out the
$50 million as a special dividend. How would you create
such a homemade special dividend
30 / 31
Question 3
ABC Co. is an all-equity firm with 50 million shares out standing. It expects FCFs of $75 million per year, and
currently has $200 million in excess cash. ABC’s cost of
capital is 10%. The CEO wants to use the excess cash
to expand ABC’s operations. This expansion will increase
free cash flows by 12%. However, the board of directors
believes that the cash should be retained. Which option
is better
31 / 31